The Once and Future Worker - Encounter Books

Free shipping on all orders over $40


The Once and Future Worker

A Vision for the Renewal of Work in America

$18.99
Add to Cart

Also Purchase as e-Book


Publication Details

Paperback / 272 pages
ISBN: 9781641771047
Available: 8/4/2020


The Once and Future Worker
A Vision for the Renewal of Work in America

The American worker is in crisis. Wages have stagnated for more than a generation. Reliance on welfare programs has surged. Life expectancy is falling as substance abuse and obesity rates climb.

These woes are not the inevitable result of irresistible global and technological forces. They are the direct consequence of a decades-long economic consensus that prioritized increasing consumption—regardless of the costs to American workers, their families, and their communities. Donald Trump’s rise to the presidency focused attention on the depth of the nation’s challenges, yet while everyone agrees something must change, the Left’s insistence on still more government spending and the Right’s faith in still more economic growth are recipes for repeating the mistakes of the past.

In this groundbreaking re-evaluation of American society, economics, and public policy, Oren Cass challenges our basic assumptions about what prosperity means and where it comes from to reveal how we lost our way. The good news is that we can still turn things around—if the nation’s proverbial elites are willing to put the American worker’s interests first.

Which is more important, pristine air quality, or well-paying jobs that support families? Unfettered access to the cheapest labor in the world, or renewed investment in the employment of Americans? Smoothing the path through college for the best students, or ensuring that every student acquires the skills to succeed in the modern economy? Cutting taxes, expanding the safety net, or adding money to low-wage paychecks?

The renewal of work in America demands new answers to these questions. If we reinforce their vital role, workers supporting strong families and communities can provide the foundation for a thriving, self-sufficient society that offers opportunity to all.


About the Author

Oren Cass is a senior fellow at the Manhattan Institute for Policy Research. He worked previously as the domestic policy director for Mitt Romney’s presidential campaign, a management consultant at Bain & Company, and an editor of the Harvard Law Review.

Read More

Praise

Excerpt

American public policy has lost its way. Since the middle of the last century, it has chased national economic growth, expecting that the benefits would be widely shared. Yet while gross domestic product (GDP) tripled from 1975 to 2015, the median worker’s wages have barely budged. Half of Americans born in 1980 were earning less at age thirty than their parents had made at that age. Millions of people have dropped out of the labor force entirely.

The primary response to the failure of rising GDP to lift all boats has been a dramatic increase in economic redistribution. Since 1975, total spending on the safety net has quadrupled. Yet the average poverty rate in the 2010s was higher than it was in the 1990s, which in turn had a higher rate than the 1970s. Analysts debate whether upward mobility has merely stalled or sharply fallen, but no one claims that it has improved. Meanwhile, families and even entire communities have collapsed; addiction has surged; life expectancy is now falling.

Rather than reversing course, policy makers wait expectantly for rescue to arrive from an education system that can transform those left behind into those getting ahead. If this were readily available, it would indeed help ease the growing crisis—and, for that matter, solve any number of society’s problems—but no such miracle appears imminent. Despite the nation doubling per-pupil spending and attempting countless education reforms, test scores look no better than they did forty years ago. Most young Americans still do not achieve even a community college degree.

With good reason, then, confidence in national institutions has eroded. Most Americans have felt the country is on the wrong track since even before the late-2000s financial crisis struck. Most Americans expect that the next generation will be worse off than themselves. Outsider candidates across the political spectrum, most notably, of course, Bernie Sanders and Donald Trump, have gained huge followings that would have seemed inconceivable only a few years earlier, simply by observing that we are in fact lost—no matter that their own road maps are flawed in important ways. Even residents of the most prosperous and cloistered enclaves are discovering that, in a democracy, a miserable majority is everyone’s problem.

This book explains where we went off-track and how we might turn around. Its argument, at its most basic, is that work matters. More specifically, it offers what I will call the Working Hypothesis: that a labor market in which workers can support strong families and communities is the central determinant of long-term prosperity and should be the central focus of public policy.

Alongside stable political institutions that protect basic freedoms, family and community provide the social structures necessary to a thriving society and a growing economy. Those institutions in turn rely on a foundation of productive work through which people find purpose and satisfaction in providing for themselves and helping others. The durable growth that produces long-term prosperity is the emergent property of a virtuous cycle in which people who are able to support their families and communities improve their own productivity and raise a subsequent generation able to accomplish even more. Conversely, without access to work that can support them, families struggle to remain intact or to form in the first place, and communities cannot help but dissolve; without stable families and communities, economic opportunity vanishes.

Economic growth and rising material living standards are laudable goals, but they by no means guarantee the health of a labor market that will meet society’s long-term needs. If we pursue growth in ways that erode the labor market’s health, and then redistribute income from the winners to the losers, we can produce impressive-looking economic statistics—for a while. But we will not generate the genuine and sustain- able prosperity that we want. Growth that consumes its own prerequisites leads inevitably to stagnation.

Regrettably, neither political party has genuinely concerned itself with work for decades. Politicians on all sides talk incessantly about “good jobs,” but the policies they pursue speak louder. What a coincidence that cutting taxes and shrinking government, expanding health care entitlements and fighting climate change, all were jobs programs as well.

Republicans have generally trusted that free markets will benefit all participants, prized the higher output associated with an “efficient” out- come, and expressed skepticism that political actors could identify and pursue better outcomes, even if any existed. Their labor-market policy could best be described as one of benign neglect.

Democrats, by contrast, can sound committed to a more worker- centric model of growth, but rather than trusting the market too much, they trample it. The party’s actual agenda centers on the interests advanced by its coalition of labor unions, environmentalists, and identity groups. Its policies rely on an expectation that government mandates and programs will deliver what the market does not.1 This agenda inserts countless regulatory wedges that aim to improve the conditions of employment but in the process raise its cost, driving apart the players that the market is attempting to connect. Better market outcomes require better market conditions; government cannot command that workers be more valuable or employment relationships be more attractive, but by trying, it can bring about the reverse.

The economic landscape is pocked with the resulting craters. Starting in the 1960s and 1970s, payroll taxes and workplace rules directly and substantially raised the cost of employing lower-wage workers. Aggressive environmental regulation reduced investment in industrial activity and thus the demand for workers whose advantage lay in relatively more physical work, while the education system’s obsession with college for all left many students ill prepared to join the labor force at all. A system of organized labor that once helped broaden prosperity began instead to hoard it for a dwindling membership, at everyone else’s expense. Our immigration system increased the supply of low-wage workers avail- able to employers by millions, while free trade increased the supply by billions—to the advantage of those seeking to use such labor, but not those seeking to provide it. All the while, an ever-expanding safety net provided more benefits to a rising share of the population, reducing work’s economic and social value.

The problem is not so much that public policy has failed as that it has succeeded at the wrong things. America is like the classic romantic- comedy heroine who, as the trailer intones, “had it all, or so she thought.” She has the prestigious job and the elegant apartment, yet she is not happy. She has pursued the wrong goals, she discovers, and to reach them, she sacrificed the things that mattered most.

We got exactly what we thought we wanted: strong overall economic growth and a large GDP, rising material living standards, a generous safety net, rapid improvements in environmental quality, extraordinarily affordable flat-screen televisions and landscaping services. Yet we gave up something we took for granted: a labor market in which the nation’s diverse array of families and communities could support themselves. This was, I will argue, the wrong trade-off, based on incorrect judgments about policies’ true costs and benefits and a poor understanding of what we were undermining. What we have been left with is a society teeter- ing atop eroded foundations, lacking structural integrity, and heading toward collapse.

*    *    *

If the Working Hypothesis is correct, neglect and mismanagement of the labor market have been the central failures of American public policy for a generation. This is infuriating, insofar as it reminds us that our prob- lems are of our own making. But a happy corollary of the hypothesis is that, if bad policy choices rather than irresistible forces or unintended consequences are responsible for the nation’s predicament, then better policy choices might help.

The economists, policy makers, and commentators who led and cheered America into the wilderness are understandably reluctant to accept responsibility. They often prefer to blame phenomena like “auto- mation” for our troubles. But that is no explanation. Technological innovation and automation have always been integral to our economic progress, and in a well-functioning labor market, they should produce gains for all types of workers. The economic data these days all point to declining productivity growth, suggesting that progress is “destroying jobs” more slowly than ever. Others continue to insist either that their policies would have worked but for the confounding influence of the other side—if only government had been smaller, with lower taxes and spending, less regulation, and thus more room for economic dynamism— or else if only government had been bigger, with more infrastructure investment, more checks on the market, a more generous safety net, and thus a prosperity more widely shared. Regardless, the prevailing consensus holds that ever more growth paired with ever more redistribution (along with, of course, the ubiquitous boosting of “skills”) must be the right solution, indeed, the only solution. Not so.

The alternative is to make trade-offs that instead place the renewal of work and family, sustained by a healthy labor market, at the center of public policy. Rather than taxing low-wage work to cut other tax rates and expand entitlements, we can do the reverse: we can provide a subsidy for low-wage work, funded with higher tax rates and reduced transfer payments. Instead of organized labor piling burdens atop the ones that federal regulators already place on employment relationships, we can repurpose unions to help workers and employers optimize workplace conditions. We can expand the demand for more of the work that more Americans can actually do if we place the concerns of the industrial economy on an equal footing with those of, say, environmentalists. We can prepare Americans to work more productively if we shift some attention and resources from the college track to the other tracks down which most people actually travel. And if we acknowledge that while the influx of foreign persons and products can greatly benefit consumers, it can also harm workers, we can even rethink our embrace of effectively open borders. If we give workers standing, if we make their productive employment an economic imperative instead of an inconvenience, the labor market can reach a healthy equilibrium.

The theme that recurs here, and throughout the book, is  one of acknowledging  trade-offs. Much pessimism about the future of work  for the typical American begins from the assumption that we cannot possibly make concessions on any of our other priorities. And yes, if  the preferences of the typical urban professional are always the most valid and important, if the maximization of economic efficiency and material  consumption  is  inviolable, if  businesses  retain  the incentive to find the cheapest possible workers anywhere in the world, then the future of the American labor market indeed looks grim. But all this merely begs the question, what should our priorities be? In the past, our society was much less affluent, and yet the typical worker could support a family. How could it be that, as we have grown wealthier as a society, we have lost the ability to make that kind of arrangement work? Or do we just not want to?

If work is foundational to our society, then we have a duty to make the changes and trade-offs necessary to support it. Certainly we cannot dismiss the goal as impossible before we even try. Nor can we dismiss it as too expensive, unless we know the alternative’s real cost. Departing from the market’s default outcome will always appear expensive if the “efficient” default is defined as the overriding social goal. But if some other outcome is better for society, then the efficient outcome is actually the more expensive one. The nations that succeed in the global economy will not be those that pledge blindest fealty to the market; they will be those that figure out which other values need to count too.

Related Titles